At the time of its enactment in 2003, the Medicare drug benefit—known as Medicare Part D—had many critics. Some said the program, which is built on consumer choice and vigorous competition among private plan options, wouldn’t work because private plans would decline to participate. Others said seniors wouldn’t sign up for the voluntary benefit because the competitive structure would be too complex. Still others said the program would explode in costs without government-regulated price controls.

All of these predictions were dead wrong. The program is now in its sixth year of operation and has exceeded all expectations. Some 90 percent of Medicare participants are now in secure drug coverage of some sort, and public opinion surveys show that seniors are very satisfied with the new program. Most importantly, the drug benefit’s costs for the first decade are coming in 42 percent below what was predicted at the time of enactment.

As this evidence of success has piled up in recent years, the critics fell silent, realizing they had little ground to stand on.

But that began to change when Congressman Paul Ryan (R–WI) proposed a broader reform of Medicare modeled on Part D’s success. And so the attacks on Part D have resumed.

The only problem is that the critics’ arguments still have no basis in fact.

Take the latest attack from Washington Post blogger Ezra Klein. He recently argued that (a) spending on prescription drugs throughout the health care system—that is, not just for Medicare—is also far below previous expectations, which proves that Part D’s market-based design had nothing to do with costs coming in under budget; (b) regardless of what has happened to date, future Part D spending is expected to rise rapidly, thus undermining claims of cost discipline; and (c) Part D premiums are actually up 57 percent in 2011 compared to 2006.

Unfortunately for Klein, each of these criticisms is easily dismissed.

In early 2004, the actuaries at the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS) issued national health expenditure projections that showed total retail prescription drug spending for the ensuing decade would reach about $3.5 trillion. In early 2010, the actuaries released new projections showing drug spending for the same 10-year period at about $2.4 trillion, or 31 percent below the previous projection. But these projections include prescription drug spending for both the elderly and non-elderly. What would the numbers look like if the drop in drug spending for the elderly (about one-third of all spending) were removed from the estimates? When that is done, the drop in projected spending for everyone else is shown to be less pronounced—just about 27 percent. So, in reality, the fall in projected spending for the elderly exceeds what it is for the rest of the population.

Moreover, there’s a real question about what precipitated the fall in projected spending system-wide in the first place. Obamacare apologists are constantly arguing that changes in Medicare have the potential to influence the entire health care market. Well, if that’s the case, it would apply to Part D as well. For instance, Part D plans have aggressively pushed generic substitution as a way to lower premiums with considerable success. Isn’t it likely that this trend among the elderly has influenced how physicians and pharmacists behave with all of their patients?

In sum, the drop in drug spending system-wide is not evidence of Part D’s irrelevance. Indeed, it reinforces the point that Part D has been effective.

Next, Klein argues, citing estimates from the CMS actuaries, that even if Part D cost escalation has been moderate in the past, it is set to rise sharply in the future. But he fails to mention that a main reason for projected cost growth going forward is that Obamacare expanded the drug benefit by closing the so-called “donut hole.” Moreover, in making these projections, the actuaries have noted that they come with great uncertainty.

Finally, Klein argues that Medicare beneficiaries are facing premiums in 2011 that are 57 percent higher than they were in 2006. This is demonstrably false. The data Klein cites is based on a subset of the program—the stand-alone drug plans—which means Medicare Advantage enrollees and those with employer-sponsored drug coverage are excluded from the calculation. Moreover, it assumes that seniors in 2011 will remain in the same plans as 2010. But the whole point of Part D’s consumer choice structure is that it allows enrollees to migrate out of plans with high costs to those with low costs. And, not surprisingly, that has happened every year of the program’s operation. The actual premiums paid by enrollees in 2011 are expected to be well below those cited by Klein.

The truth that Klein and others seem unwilling to face is that Part D has been a phenomenal success story. From 2006 to 2010, per capita Part D costs across all settings have risen by an average of just 1.2 percent annually, which is well below the per capita cost growth for the rest of Medicare.

The key to the drug benefit’s early success is engaged consumers. Seniors want to get the best value for their Part D premium, and that means looking for low premium plans with good coverage. The result has been a record of cost-control that government micromanagement has never matched—and never will.

A fellow at the Ethics and Public Policy Center, Capretta is the co-author of Why Obamacare is Wrong for America (HarperCollins/Broadside, 2011).